$5,900 chair may be the tech world's new key to productivity

http://ift.tt/2dJZO7t


Che Voigt believes his company has solved problems that have plagued the working world since the advent of typing. 

It’s a solution to hunched backs, stiff necks and tight shoulders. It’s a workstation that, with a push of a button, transitions from a standing desk to a seated table to a fully reclined platform like a dentist’s chair. Its seat expands and retracts, supporting the whole body from head to heels. Its desk moves up, down and rotates. There’s a screen and mouse and keyboard that follows the user’s eyes and hands. 

It’s the way of the future, he says; the most comfortable you can possible be working at a computer. And it starts at $5,900.

Before anyone scoffs, Voigt has a defense: 1) Don’t knock it until you’ve tried it, and 2) If people don’t invest in ergonomics now, they’ll pay for it later.

And if Silicon Valley’s track record is anything to go by, Voigt might be onto something. Tech firms have long embraced wacky inventions that promise heightened productivity and creativity — and the industry has a history of making them mainstream. 

Height-adjustable desks and $1,000 Herman Miller chairs that once seemed extravagant are no longer just common at software start-ups; schools, government agencies and even the White House have gotten on board. Whether it’s open floor plans, ergonomic keyboards or yoga ball chairs, workplaces far removed from the tech world often co-opt the quirky and often costly office cultures of firms like Apple, Google and Facebook in hope that some of their success rubs off. 

“Comfort is material to creativity,” said Voigt, 45, chief executive of Altwork, a company that builds each workstation by hand in a barn on a 65-acre family property shared with Zinfandel wine grapes in Sonoma County. “If you’re stressed or distressed, the mind can’t fall into creativity. We want to get into an area where you can be productive and do really good work.”

Twenty years ago, ergonomics was about finding a decent office chair and doing the occasional stretch throughout the day, said Joy Boese, an ergonomics specialist at E3 Consulting who has worked with companies such as Toyota and Netflix. It was considered an office perk, something filed in the “nice to have” category. Today, particularly in tech land, it’s expected.

“Now it’s about tracking your health, tracking your steps, seeing how you spend your day, integrating fitness desks, treadmill desks, Zen rooms for people to take a moment to rest their mind,” Boese said. “These companies want people to feel like it’s more than just coming to work — they want a happy, healthy, engaged workforce.”

Silicon Valley is at the forefront of this, Boese said, which is no surprise, given that it is traditionally “two to three years ahead of the curve.”

But it’s also characteristic of the Valley’s ruthless optimization and productivity ethos. 

It was software engineers who popularized Soylent, the liquid meal replacement for techies. It was tech CEOs such as Mark Zuckerberg and Steve Jobs who streamlined their wardrobes into a uniform, a move that Zuckerberg has justified saying it helped “clear my life so that I have to make as few decisions as possible… on things that are silly or frivolous.” And it was the tech world that normalized “lockdowns” — intense work periods when employees don’t leave the office until a project is done.

These cultural quirks reflect the immense pressure that many tech workers face to deliver big projects on tight deadlines, justifying not only their own salaries but also their companies’ lofty valuations. The Altwork Station is designed for these people, said Voigt, who describes them as “high-intensity computer users.”

“Being comfortable at your desk is really important,” said Helen Wu, director of growth partnerships at San Francisco tech firm AppLovin, where every employee can choose between a sitting or standing desk and request ergonomic gadgets. Wu herself doesn’t have an Altwork Station, but she uses a laptop stand on her desk, an ergonomic keyboard and a Handshoe mouse — a wireless gadget that looks like a fedora made for aliens — from the Netherlands. 

“Having a setup where you don’t have to worry about your physiology lets you focus on your work,” she said.

The tech industry isn’t unique when it comes to valuing productivity. Wall Street, which has a reputation for brutal efficiency and long hours, has also invested in ergonomics. What sets Silicon Valley apart, according to ergonomics specialists who have worked with both industries, is its lack of self-consciousness and its willingness to go all-in. 

That’s why five-toe shoes (with separate nooks for each toe, like a glove for the foot) and telepresence robots — tablet computers on rolling pedestals that offer off-site employees an in-person presence — are not uncommon on tech campuses, but remain rare in New York’s Financial District. 

“We worked with a brokerage firm to redesign their office into an open plan space, and it was hard to get people out of private offices,” said Melissa Steach, an ergonomics specialist at Herman Miller, the furniture firm whose midcentury designs are now ubiquitous in the tech industry. “There was a lot of ego attached to it, the whole ‘I’m a baller, I’ve earned this office and you don’t have one.’ ” 

Silicon Valley, meanwhile, isn’t wary of workplace weirdness. It has embraced it — reclining chairs, bike-pedal footstools, treadmill desks and all.

There’s a copycat element to it too, said Michael Lukasik, a brand development manager for West Elm Workspace, an arm of the housewares business that furnishes offices. Start-ups often express Google-shaped aspirations even if their businesses couldn’t be further from Google’s.

“These smaller companies are coming to us and saying, ‘We saw images of Google’s offices — can you help us accomplish this?’” Lukasik said. “Everyone wants to attract the same talent that Google or Apple attracts and retains.”

It doesn’t always work, of course. The Googles and Facebooks of the world were at least bringing in revenue before they started lavishing their employees with ergonomic perks. Some start-ups find themselves in the reverse situation, spending big before they’ve hit the jackpot.

“It’s not unusual to hear that some company just got a round of financing and bought 20 [Herman Miller] Aeron chairs, or that another just bought 40 at a discount from another start-up that went bust,” said Mike Vorhaus, Silicon Valley and technology analyst. “I absolutely think this is a follow-the-leader thing.”

Still, many tech firms swear by it, reporting that ergonomic furniture has led to happier, healthier and more productive employees.

In Culver City, underwear subscription start-up MeUndies has an office decked out in Herman Miller furniture, with $660 chairs,  $1,000 sit-to-stand desks and an open floor plan designed by ergonomists. 

“The most telling stat is employee retention,” said Terry Lee, MeUndies’ chief operating officer. “In the two years I’ve been here we’ve only had two employees voluntarily leave. In less than a year we’ve doubled our headcount. I think it translates to employee happiness, and workplace ergonomics tie into that.”

For most companies, the draw of ergonomics is the effect that it is believed to have on the bottom line. 

“The companies buying these know if they can get their project done a little sooner, it pays huge dividends,” Voigt said. If a company could squeeze even 10 more minutes of worker efficiency each day, then the cost of an Altwork Station “is completely insignificant,” he said.

Voigt is a mechanical engineer by trade and spent most of his career working on aerospace systems. He started on the Altwork Station five years ago when a family friend, who couldn’t sit for for long periods of time because of an injury, came to him with the idea of a chair that would let him work in repose. 

Voigt didn’t think the project would take long. After all, how hard could it be to design a chair? 

“Well, it’s not just a chair,” he said. “You have to have a desk, and you have to learn about the human body, you have to figure out what to do with devices, and there are all these wonderful problems to solve to get it right.”

The Altwork Station is pricier than comparable offerings from Herman Miller and Steelcase, but it’s more adjustable and, according to Voigt, the transitions are more seamless. Users can set their ideal position and the station will remember it.

Some of the Valley’s biggest tech companies have already expressed interest in the Altwork Station, although Voigt wouldn’t say which ones. The company, backed by self-funding and $3 million from angel investors, started shipping pre-orders this week.

Although he understands that productivity is probably the desk’s strongest selling point, Voigt insists that the Altwork Station is a solution to neck, shoulder and back contortions we perform every day just to use a computer. 

“Humans have created all these fantastic things while hunched over a computer,” he said. “The fact that we’ve advanced all this tech but haven’t supported our body in any different way is insane to me.”

tracey.lien@latimes.com

Twitter: @traceylien

ALSO

Silicon Valley's 'try before you buy' tech showroom is coming to Santa Monica

How to spend $70 million entertaining the under-35 crowd

Burn calories as you work without buying an expensive treadmill desk



from Hacker News http://ift.tt/YV9WJO
via IFTTT

Why It's So Hard to Stop Bad Cops From Getting New Jobs: New at Reason

http://ift.tt/2dxcyiU

White House Photo / Chuck KennedyWhite House Photo / Chuck KennedyDepending on the state you live in, you may be required to obtain an occupational license to become a plumber, an insurance agent, a hair braider, a manicurist, or even a racetrack employee. These licenses, which can take dozens or hundreds of hours of training to procure, afford privileged access to specific industries—and they can be revoked if certain standards aren't met. But in six states, the same standard isn't applied to one surprising profession: law enforcement.

Massachusetts, New York, New Jersey, Rhode Island, California, and Hawaii employ 26 percent of this country's law enforcement officers, according to the Bureau of Justice Statistics. But they have no legal authority to revoke the licenses of cops who have been dismissed for misconduct. And even though the other 44 states can decertify police officers, there is no nationwide mechanism allowing every police department in the country to access an applicant's work history with out-of-state departments. This information gap allows officers banned from working as police in one state to secure law enforcement employment in another state.

Police representatives would have you believe that "gypsy cops," as such officers are sometimes referred to, represent an overstated and barely existent threat at best. In March 2016, Ray McGrath, the legislative director of the International Brotherhood of Police Officers (IBPO)—one of the U.S.'s most prominent police unions—told members of the Massachusetts legislature, "It's not possible for an officer [fired for misconduct] to get another job in civil service,"according to a state House reporter for Boston University.

But bad cops can and do find work in law enforcement. Decertified police have repeatedly slipped through the cracks to find new jobs in the profession, often by moving to another state and applying to a department lacking the resources or manpower to do a thorough background check.

Although some efforts to track police decertifications exist, they are scattered and fragmented, varying from state to state, with no unified national coordination. That's why police reform advocates have been pushing for the creation of a single, federally maintained database for more than 20 years.



from Hit & Run : Reason Magazine https://reason.com/blog
via IFTTT

Why Hedge Funds Remain The Worst Performing Asset Class Of 2016

http://ift.tt/2cNGFx6

It's been a bad year for hedge funds as a result of significantly underperforming the market, coupled with the biggest wave of redemptions since the financial crisis. Unfortunately, according to the latest Goldman data, there is no reprieve in sight. As the following chart from David Kostin shows, both global macro hedge funds and equity long short funds are the worst performing assets YTD on both a total return and risk-adjusted basis.

There are two main reasons why hedge funds continue to underperform: on one hand correlations across various sectors have soared to the highest levels in the past three years, leading to a plunge in return dispersion making "stock-picking" virtually impossible...

... while on the other hand, the most popular hedge fund short positions have soared in recent months, crushing short books and more than offsetting the modest rebound in the "hedge fund VIP" basket of most popular positions.

And while hedge funds have continued to underperform, several outright sectors continue to dramatically outperform the S&P, most notably IT, followed by Consumer Staples, Telecom and Utilities, even if the latter three have seen some modest weakness in recent months as a result of the pick up in yields.

... leading to the following most recent return by sector, where despite the recent surge in IT, Utilities still have the YTD lead, followed closely by Telecom and Energy.

Shifting away from sectors, and focusing only on valuation factors, we find that size (in this case small is better), high margins and low dividend yield have become increasingly expensive, while on the other end, low momentum, low margins and high volatility are now the cheapest inputs into quant models.

Shifting back out, we then look at the overall market where we find the valuations on both an absolute and relative basis remain especially rich, with the S&P trading at a 17.3x forward PE, and while financials and telecom remain cheap, at 12.6x and 13.9x fwd PE respectively, they are more than offset by the lunacy in Energy stocks which trade at over 43x, while consumer staples is the second richest sector currently.

Finally, putting it all together shows that mutual fund outflows continue, with some $127 billion withdrawn from equity mutual funds, and even ETFs now negative YTD; both of these are more than offset by the $110 billion in inflows in bond mutual funds and ETFs, while as a result of the upcoming change to money market fund regulation, those particular funds keep bleeding cash, having lost some $124 billion YTD. Also worth noting, a marketwide short squeeze as a drive of upside is no longer a key concern as a result of the S&P's median short interest as a % of market cap sliding to 2.4%: the lowest since last summer.



from Zero Hedge http://ift.tt/qouXdu
via IFTTT

Silicon Valley's Secrets Are Hiding in Marc Andreessen's Library

http://ift.tt/2cadd8u

The first time I walked into the lobby of Andreessen Horowitz, four guys were waiting near the wall. Two sat in chairs. Two stood. And all four peered into open laptops, anxiously reviewing the slide decks they would soon pitch to the firm’s partners. Founded in 2009 by Marc Andreessen and his buddy Ben Horowitz, the firm is one of more than 40 venture capital shops lined up along Sand Hill Road, a short stretch of asphalt in Palo Alto, California, that winds into the heart of Stanford University. Sand Hill Road is where people pitch their ideas to Silicon Valley, and the Andreessen lobby is now the highest-profile, highest-stakes lobby of them all.

These 800 books are a microcosm of both Hollywood and Silicon Valley—at the same time.

I came to chat with a few of the firm’s partners and maybe stumble onto a story or two. I didn’t have a slide deck to review. But this lobby is also a library, with books stretching nearly from the floor to the ceiling. So I stepped to the closest shelf and scanned a few spines. Then I did a double-take and scanned them again. Kevin Brownlow’s The Parade’s Gone By. Neil Gabler’s An Empire of Their Own. A. Scott Berg’s Samuel Goldwyn. Carol Beauchamp’s Joseph P. Kennedy Presents. All these books explore the early days of Hollywood, and every one of them also sits on a shelf in my living room at home. I happen to be a film buff, you see, and so was someone at Andreessen Horowitz.

The lobby also offers myriad books on computer programming and the Silicon Valley ethos, like John Markoff’s What the Dormouse Said and Clayton Christensen’s The Innovator’s Dilemma. And other sections extend beyond Hollywood. There’s the history of news media. The history of radio. David Halberstam’s The Powers That Be. Leslie Klinger’s Annotated Sherlock Holmes. The complete works of Charles Schulz (you know: Peanuts). A shelf and half of Pogo (The hipster’s Peanuts). But the movie books are what hooked me. The Parade’s Gone By is the definitive history of the silent era. Samuel Goldwyn is the very best of the Hollywood biographies. These weren’t books chosen at random. They belonged to someone with a very real and very deep interest.

So I started asking where these books came from and what they meant. And eventually, I found some answers. But it wasn’t easy. The Andreessen library is very real, but it’s also surrounded by several layers of artifice. These 800 books are a microcosm of both Hollywood and Silicon Valley, at the same time.

Who the Devil Made It

In 1908, the country’s nine largest filmmakers formed the Movie Picture Patents Company, insisting that no one else could make movies because they controlled the patents on the original movie camera, co-created by Thomas Edison at his lab in New Jersey. The patents belonged to Edison, and he backed the Patents Company. So a new wave of filmmakers moved to the West Coast, where the courts were less friendly to Edison. Hollywood became a place to make movies in part because it was so sunny—you could film outdoors more often and with fewer lights—but also because it was so far away from New Jersey.

DK_Wired_080516-171.jpgDrew Kelly for WIRED

Who the Devil Made It—an oral history of Hollywood collected by the director and film historian Peter Bogdanovich—begins in the days of the Patents Company. Allan Dwan, who started making movies in the 1910s, tells Bogdanovich that as independent filmmakers moved west, the Patents Company hired strongmen to enforce its patents. Dwan remembers snipers climbing trees overlooking movie sets and taking shots at the cameras they deemed illegal. He would film as far as he could from the railroad stops, so he and his crew were harder to find.

The story of early Hollywood is very much the story of Silicon Valley, full of innovators fleeing the old rules in search of the new. It only makes sense that the lobby of Andreessen Horowitz is stocked with books on early Hollywood, including Who The Devil Made It. Bogdanovich and Dwan tell a story not unlike the one told in What the Dormouse Said, where a group of freethinkers rise up in the 1960s and create the personal computer, pushing against entrenched giants like IBM.

I asked Chris Dixon, one of the firm’s partners, about the books. “That’s all Marc,” he said. He meant Marc Andreessen, and if you spend even a little time following Silicon Valley—or if you subscribe to The New Yorker, which published a 13,000-word profile on the man last summer—you know who he is. If you didn’t read the profile, I can summarize: Marc Andreessen helped create the web browser that launched the Internet age. He’s now a VC. He has a really big noggin.

The story of early Hollywood is very much the story of Silicon Valley, full of innovators fleeing the old rules in search of the new.

Dixon says that in the firm’s earliest days, Andreessen pulled most of those books from his personal collection at home. And that’s all he really knew. But if it was all Marc, it was also a little bit Michael Ovitz. As The New Yorker explains, Andreessen and Horowitz are pals with Ovitz, the guy behind CAA, one of Hollywood’s biggest talent agencies. When they started their firm, they went to Ovitz for advice.

“Call everyone a partner, offer services the others don’t, and help people who aren’t your clients,” he said. “Disrupt to differentiate by becoming a dream-execution machine.” They did all that. And, in contrast to typical Silicon Valley VCs, they hired a whole team of publicists who guided Andreessen Horowitz stories into Fortune and Forbes. They hung some Rauschenbergs around the office—just like CAA. And when people pitched them, they drank from glassware rather than plastic. The books complement the Rauschenbergs and the glassware. They, too, lend authority.

Ovitz is also a connection to Hollywood. But that’s not why so many of the books are about Hollywood. That really is all Marc.

DK_Wired_080516-100-z.jpgDrew Kelly for WIRED

The Star Machine

Old Hollywood, writes Jeanine Basinger in The Star Machine, another book in the Andreessen lobby, was a factory that built illusions. It transformed ordinary men and women into “the gods and goddesses known as a movie stars.” Take Julia Jean Mildred Frances Turner. Born in an Idaho mining town, she landed a Hollywood agent after the editor of The Hollywood Reporter spotted her drinking a Coke in Currie’s Candy and Cigar Store, across the street from Hollywood High School.

Later, as she rose to fame at MGM, the star machine didn’t just change her name and her clothes and her voice. It remade her story. She wasn’t Julia Jean Mildred Francis. She was Lana. She wasn’t discovered at Currie’s drinking a Coke. She was discovered at Schwab’s Drugstore drinking a chocolate malted, because that sounded better. The studios were shameless about spinning things their way, and the press was shameless about spinning things the same way to keep on the good side of the studios.

This is how Silicon Valley works too. It makes stars, shaping their origin stories into legends like the one about Lana Turner and Schwab’s Drugstore.

This is how Silicon Valley works too. It makes stars, shaping their origin stories into legends like the one about Lana Turner and Schwab’s Drugstore. Evan Williams and Biz Stone creating Twitter with Jack Dorsey at Odeo. Uber CEO Travis Kalanick and the Paris cab shortage. Theranos founder Elizabeth Holmes and her childhood fear of needles.

After discussing all those books with all sorts of people, I pitched the story to my editors: The tale of Silicon Valley told through Marc Andreessen’s library, including the Pogo. They liked it, but they wanted pictures of the library. So I asked the firm’s PR team for an interview with Andreessen and a chance to photograph the books. And they said no.

They were very nice about it, but they said the firm was overexposed, pointing to that New Yorker profile. Then they added that Andreessen was a new dad. And I have to say: None of that quite made sense to me. After all, Andreessen Horowitz is a firm built on overexposure. On Twitter, Marc Andreessen broadcasts his thoughts to the world with a fervor that outstrips almost anyone. He invented the “tweet storm.” All I wanted to do was talk about the books in the lobby. I wanted to write about something real, and the artifice got in the way.

Drew Kelly for WIRED

The Whole Equation

The title of David Thompson’s 2006 Hollywood history, The Whole Equation, is a nod to an oft-quoted passage about Hollywood in F. Scott Fitzgerald’s unfinished novel The Last Tycoon. “It can be understood,” it reads, “but only dimly and in flashes. Not half a dozen men have ever been able to keep the whole equation of pictures in their heads.”

That’s a fair assessment of early Hollywood. It was an ever-changing mix of business, technology, art, and, yes, artifice. Some people, like Joseph P. Kennedy, the father of President John Kennedy, understood the financial side. Some, like Kennedy’s partner, David Sarnoff, the head of RCA, understood how the technology drove the business. Some, like D.W. Griffith, understood how the technology drove the art. Everybody was good at artifice. And a few people, like Irving Thalberg, the head of production at MGM, understood it all—or at least they understood it all as well anyone really could.

DK_Wired_080516-172.jpgDrew Kelly for WIRED

Silicon Valley blends these same threads, including the art. Today, after all, it’s even subsuming what Hollywood does, making its own movies and TV shows. Rather than go to the theater, we go to our smartphones and tablets. Netflix and Amazon are now movie studios. Facebook and Oculus are building the kind of immersive media that Hollywood never could—a movement driven, in part, by Chris Dixon and Andreessen Horowitz. Of course the lobby is lined with movie books.

I finally talked to Andreessen, and I asked him about the book collection. He said he didn’t like the lobbies at other VC firms. They looked like “monuments to themselves” filled with “tombstones”—framed IPO prospectus covers and Lucite statues that investment bankers give out when you sell a startup. “It felt like visiting the lobby of an insurance company—instead of somebody you would presumably really want to talk to,” he says. So he filled his own lobby with books. He spent three nights sorting the titles for maximum effect. Programming books on one set of shelves, Hollywood books on another, business books on a third, and so on.

The arrangement didn’t last. As people move through that lobby, they browse the books, flip through them, and inevitably put them back in the wrong place. Sometimes a Steve Jobs book winds up in the middle of all those books about Orson Welles. And as authors and publicists come through, many of them slot in their own books—sometimes in bulk. When I mention the collection to Antonio García Martínez, a startup founder and former Facebooker who wrote the Silicon Valley memoir Chaos Monkeys: Obscene Fortune and Random Failure in Silicon Valley, he asks how he can get a copy into the lobby. The misplaced books and volunteer titles annoy Andreessen. “I don’t sit in that room,” he says, “so I can’t control it.” But make no mistake: Andreessen is the room. And the room still has the desired effect: It makes you want to talk to the people inside.

Make no mistake: Andreessen is the room. And the room still has the desired effect: It makes you want to talk to the people inside.

What’s more, it doesn’t mislead. These really are people worth talking to. Andreessen has a wonderfully entertaining way of deconstructing just about anything that comes up, whether it’s AI healthcare or Joseph P. Kennedy. Andreessen says that Joseph P. Kennedy Presents, which chronicles the banker’s time as a Hollywood movie mogul, is one of his favorite books, and he calls Kennedy “the one who wasn’t like the others.” That sums up Kennedy, and it sums up Andreessen too. Both were outsiders (Kennedy an Irish Catholic Bostonian among Jewish immigrant traders from New York, Andreessen a computer nerd among financiers). “He’s someone who looks at society and says interesting things,” García Martínez says of Andreessen, “which is unlike most VCs, who are total followers and don’t have much interesting to say about the world.”

Many of Andreessen’s partners are cut from the same cloth, including Dixon. That doesn’t necessarily mean these folks will outperform the Valley’s other VCs. After a recent article in The Wall Street Journal questioning the firm’s performance to date—and a carefully constructed response from Andreessen Horowitz—Valley insiders continue to debate the firm’s money-making talents. But the Andreessen partners certainly get the equation.

DK_Wired_080516-89-z.jpgDrew Kelly for WIRED

An Empire of Their Own

Neil Gabler’s An Empire of Their Own chronicles the Eastern European Jewish immigrants who created Hollywood from nothing. Adolph Zukor of Paramount. Louis B. Mayer of MGM. Carl Laemmle of Universal. William Fox (born Wilhelm Fried) of Fox. The Warner Brothers (previously Wonskolaser). In the 1920s and 1930s, their studios grew to dominate the industry and American popular culture.

In the beginning, Andreessen tells me, Hollywood was a frontier, just as Silicon Valley is a frontier today. He calls the movie business the other great “organic” California industry. “The idea of going West for unclaimed land? That era was over by the 1870s, the 1880s,” he says. “But California remained the frontier for the purpose of creating new industries—starting first with entertainment and then with tech.”

Today, Andreessen says, we think of Hollywood as the establishment. But in the early days, it pushed against the establishment. As we chat, he mentions the Patents Company and how the filmmakers went west in an effort to escape its patents, strongmen, and snipers. “Talk about disruption,” he says, with an all-out belly laugh. When you read about the early days of Hollywood, he says, you’re apt to think that happened in Cupertino last week. Patents Company or no Patents Company, Silicon Valley moves ahead. It’s an attitude that drives Google and Facebook and Uber and Airbnb. “If everybody obeyed the rules all the time,” Andreessen says, “nothing would ever happen.”

DK_Wired_080516-128.jpgDrew Kelly for WIRED

Of course, Hollywood changed. And, well, Silicon Valley is changing too. Just like Hollywood in the late ’20s and early ’30s, it’s becoming a power center. Just as Paramount, MGM, Universal, Fox, and Warner Brothers came to dominate film, a few big players are taking control of the tech world. Google. Facebook. Apple. Amazon. They control the infrastructure that makes everything go.

That’s why so many people build their companies in Silicon Valley. It’s where the big players are, and it’s where the money is—VCs like Andreessen Horowitz, who control so much of the funding and have so many hooks into those big tech players. For all the talk of frontiers and disruption, Silicon Valley is now morphing into the thing it once fought against. “It’s going from being the Steve Jobs/Wozniak thing of disrupting the establishment to becoming the establishment,” says García Martínez. That’s what happens to frontiers: They get civilized.

Right before I plan to ask Andreessen about that, his PR handler cuts the interview short. That’s what happens when you’re part of the establishment. But as always, the answer lies in his book collection. It also includes a book called Pictures at a Revolution. It’s about the Hollywood studio system losing its grip in the 1960s, as it was undercut by new, outside forces including television, the European New Wave, and the American counterculture. Eventually, the new establishment always buckles under something even newer.

Go Back to Top. Skip To: Start of Article.


from Hacker News http://ift.tt/YV9WJO
via IFTTT

Silicon Valley Wages Now Double US Average

http://ift.tt/2djNzLm

The Bay Area’s wages are getting higher, far outpacing most of the country, but more residents are finding their paychecks can’t keep up with the region’s skyrocketing cost of living.

The typical Silicon Valley income — well over $100,000 annually — is now double the national average, according to a Bay Area News Group analysis of ten years of federal data. But while pay here is soaring, the cost of housing is rising even faster.

Even workers in technology — the sector driving the region’s economic boom — are finding out that the “haves” don’t always have enough. And for those making far less, the prospects are grim.

“We have a two-income family — we both make good money — but it seems like every month, the expenses keep rising,” said Nicole Tembrevilla, a recruiter for an East Bay tech company. Together, Tembrevilla and her husband, who own a home in San Ramon, make in the low $200,000 range.

A senior recruiter Nicole Tembrevilla poses for a photograph in Pleasanton, Calif., on Wednesday, Sept. 14, 2016. (Anda Chu/Bay Area News Group)Together, Nicole Tembrevilla and her husband make well above the average wage in the East Bay, but she says trying to keep up with the region’s cost of living is “overwhelming.” Anda Chu/Staff

“It’s hard to save money,” said Tembrevilla, who lives in San Ramon with her husband and two children, one in high school and the other in middle school. “It’s home improvements, the car, car insurance, tuition — it’s overwhelming. And we’re trying to save up for college.”

Residents say the biggest obstacle to making ends meet is simple: The Bay Area’s mammoth home prices and soaring rents.

“I’m getting good pay raises, but you really have to make around $150,000 a year to be able to afford a house around here,” said Joseph Martin, of Mountain View, a systems administrator with a San Jose tech company. Martin says he makes in the high five-figure range. “The real question is, ‘How do you afford to find a place to live here?’”

For those making below the average wage, owning a home is out of reach. They’re just trying to survive.

Christine Zeyen and her boyfriend moved to San Jose from Arizona a few months ago, hoping to improve their financial and work situation.

“We are just barely making ends meet,” said Zeyen, as she shopped at a San Jose thrift store. “The expenses here are a real eye-opener.”

Zeyen works about 30 hours a week in behavioral therapy and receives financial help from her father to boost her income to roughly $25,000 annually. Her boyfriend makes about $60,000 a year working for Frito Lay. But in San Jose, that’s far from enough.

“It takes everything we have to pay the bills,” Zeyen said. “We moved here to make a better future for ourselves. It’s hard to say if it’s worth it.”

sjm-wages-0925-90Over the last five years, average wages in the Bay Area’s five most populous counties have risen by roughly 30 percent. In those same five years, the period of recovery and economic expansion after the Great Recession, home prices in those counties have soared more than 87 percent. In the more affordable East Bay, the median home price has doubled.

The gap between wages and home prices isn’t the only disparity underscored by this news organization’s analysis of wage trends in the Bay Area.

Wages in the three counties with higher concentrations of technology companies far outpace those in counties with relatively few tech jobs. At the end of June, Santa Clara County had 344,700 tech jobs, and the East Bay had 137,400. At the end of March, annual pay averaged $114,920 in Santa Clara County, $114,140 in San Mateo County and $106,808 in San Francisco, according to the federal government’s closely watched Quarterly Census of Employment and Wages.

But in the East Bay, wages averaged $70,356 in Alameda County and $66,820 in Contra Costa County,

“The Bay Area is a tale of three different economies,” said Jon Haveman, principal economist with San Rafael-based Marin Economic Consulting. “You have Santa Clara County, the Peninsula and San Francisco with extremely high-wage jobs. You have the East Bay, which has good wages and is more middle-income, along with Marin.”

And Sonoma and Solano have even lower average wages.

The Quarterly Census figures show the pay gap between the Bay Area region and the rest of the country is accelerating.

In large part, that’s because tech companies fuel the Bay Area’s economic engine — and its surge in wages. Firms often dangle big paychecks, bonuses and stock options as part of the scramble to lure talent and retain prized workers.

“The war for talent is driving all of this,” said Russell Hancock, president of Joint Venture Silicon Valley. “… The tech boom and wage growth have created a class of the uber-rich in the Bay Area.”

Still, strong paydays in the technology industry aren’t always enough, as tech worker Martin has discovered.

Martin said he and his girlfriend, a preschool teacher, hope to buy a house in Mountain View, Sunnyvale, Santa Clara or San Francisco. They want to avoid the grind of commuting from the Central Valley or other outlying areas, but the harsh reality of home prices in the $800,000, $900,000 or even $1 million range has jolted them.

“It’s crazy how expensive homes are,” said Martin, 26. “I don’t know too many people my age who can afford the homes here.”

Case in point: Over the five years that ended in July, the median home price has rocketed up 94 percent in San Mateo County, 74 percent in Santa Clara County and 67 percent in San Francisco, according to figures from the CoreLogic real estate information service. While the median in the East Bay is lower, home prices there have increased even more: up 105 percent in Contra Costa County and up 99 percent in Alameda County.

Bay Area poverty rates dipped for the first time in 10 years, according to recent census data, but in the metropolitan region of San Francisco, Hayward and Oakland alone, there were still 485,000 people living in poverty in 2015. That’s just a slight dip from the 491,000 in poverty in 2014.

“The rising cost of living is creating poverty,” said Micah Weinberg, president of the Bay Area Council Economic Institute, singling out the region’s increasing home prices.

Silicon Valley’s concentration of tech workers, with their top-flight paychecks, increases the chances that people will bid up housing values.

“The high earners who are doing really well, they are paying cash for houses, and the rest of us can’t do that,” Hancock said. “Most people can’t compete in the housing market. That’s created a brutal environment in Silicon Valley.”

Ben Mohr, a San Ramon-based retirement planner who works with a cross-section of people, hears plenty of stories about the challenges of living in this region.

“You have to make a lot of money just to keep up with how much things cost here,” Mohr said. “What’s happening in the Bay Area reminds you of what you see in places like Manhattan.”

Vanessa Cueva, who lives in Tracy and works for a staffing services firm in Pleasanton, would like a shorter commute. But the reality, she says, is you have to go where the jobs are.

“I would try to find a job in the Central Valley, but there really isn’t as much work there,” said Cueva. “So I have to commute back and forth. That is a hard hour, hour-and-a-half of driving.”

The pattern of sharply rising wages in Silicon Valley is likely to persist, experts say.

“Demand for hiring is going to continue,” said Stephen Levy, director of the Palo Alto-based Center for Continuing Study of the California Economy. “And that will keep the upward pressure on wages in Silicon Valley.”



from Hacker News http://ift.tt/YV9WJO
via IFTTT

The Most Intolerant Wins: The Dictatorship of the Small Minority

http://ift.tt/2bLzSmh


The Most Intolerant Wins: The Dictatorship of the Small Minority

How Europe will eat Halal — Why you don’t have to smoke in the smoking section — Your food choices on the fall of the Saudi king –How to prevent a friend from working too hard –Omar Sharif ‘s conversion — How to make a market collapse

T he best example I know that gives insights into the functioning of a complex system is with the following situation. It suffices for an intransigent minority –a certain type of intransigent minorities –to reach a minutely small level, say three or four percent of the total population, for the entire population to have to submit to their preferences. Further, an optical illusion comes with the dominance of the minority: a naive observer would be under the impression that the choices and preferences are those of the majority. If it seems absurd, it is because our scientific intuitions aren’t calibrated for that (fughedabout scientific and academic intuitions and snap judgments; they don’t work and your standard intellectualization fails with complex systems, though not your grandmothers’ wisdom).

The main idea behind complex systems is that the ensemble behaves in way not predicted by the components. The interactions matter more than the nature of the units. Studying individual ants will never (one can safely say never for most such situations), never give us an idea on how the ant colony operates. For that, one needs to understand an ant colony as an ant colony, no less, no more, not a collection of ants. This is called an “emergent” property of the whole, by which parts and whole differ because what matters is the interactions between such parts. And interactions can obey very simple rules. The rule we discuss in this chapter is the minority rule.

The minority rule will show us how it all it takes is a small number of intolerant virtuous people with skin in the game, in the form of courage, for society to function properly.

This example of complexity hit me, ironically, as I was attending the New England Complex Systems institute summer barbecue. As the hosts were setting up the table and unpacking the drinks, a friend who was observant and only ate Kosher dropped by to say hello. I offered him a glass of that type of yellow sugared water with citric acid people sometimes call lemonade, almost certain that he would reject it owing to his dietary laws. He didn’t. He drank the liquid called lemonade, and another Kosher person commented: “liquids around here are Kosher”. We looked at the carton container. There was a fine print: a tiny symbol, a U inside a circle, indicating that it was Kosher. The symbol will be detected by those who need to know and look for the minuscule print. As to others, like myself, I had been speaking prose all these years without knowing, drinking Kosher liquids without knowing they were Kosher liquids.

Figure 1 The lemonade container with the circled U indicating it is (literally) Kosher.

Criminals With Peanut Allergies

A strange idea hit me. The Kosher population represents less than three tenth of a percent of the residents of the United States. Yet, it appears that almost all drinks are Kosher. Why? Simply because going full Kosher allows the producer, grocer, restaurant, to not have to distinguish between Kosher and nonkosher for liquids, with special markers, separate aisles, separate inventories, different stocking sub-facilities. And the simple rule that changes the total is as follows:

A Kosher (or halal) eater will never eat nonkosher (or nonhalal) food , but a nonkosher eater isn’t banned from eating kosher.

Or, rephrased in another domain:

A disabled person will not use the regular bathroom but a nondisabled person will use the bathroom for disabled people.

Granted, sometimes, in practice, we hesitate to use the bathroom with the disabled sign on it owing to some confusion –mistaking the rule for the one for parking cars, under the belief that the bathroom is reserved for exclusive use by the handicapped.

Someone with a peanut allergy will not eat products that touch peanuts but a person without such allergy can eat items without peanut traces in them.

Which explains why it is so hard to find peanuts on airplanes and why schools are peanut-free (which, in a way, increases the number of persons with peanut allergies as reduced exposure is one of the causes behind such allergies).

Let us apply the rule to domains where it can get entertaining:

An honest person will never commit criminal acts but a criminal will readily engage in legal acts.

Let us call such minority an intransigent group, and the majority a flexible one. And the rule is an asymmetry in choices.

I once pulled a prank on a friend. Years ago when Big Tobacco were hiding and repressing the evidence of harm from secondary smoking, New York had smoking and nonsmoking sections in restaurants (even airplanes had, absurdly, a smoking section). I once went to lunch with a friend visiting from Europe: the restaurant only had availability in the smoking sections. I convinced the friend that we needed to buy cigarettes as we had to smoke in the smoking section. He complied.

Two more things. First, the geography of the terrain, that is, the spatial structure, matters a bit; it makes a big difference whether the intransigents are in their own district or are mixed with the rest of the population. If the people following the minority rule lived in Ghettos, with their separate small economy, then the minority rule would not apply. But, when a population has an even spatial distribution, say the ratio of such a minority in a neighborhood is the same as that in the village, that in the village is the same as in the county, that in the county is the same as that in state, and that in the sate is the same as nationwide, then the (flexible) majority will have to submit to the minority rule. Second, the cost structure matters quite a bit. It happens in our first example that making lemonade compliant with Kosher laws doesn’t change the price by much, not enough to justify inventories. But if the manufacturing of Kosher lemonade cost substantially more, then the rule will be weakened in some nonlinear proportion to the difference in costs. If it cost ten times as much to make Kosher food, then the minority rule will not apply, except perhaps in some very rich neighborhoods.

Muslims have Kosher laws so to speak, but these are much narrower and apply only to meat. For Muslim and Jews have near-identical slaughter rules (all Kosher is halal for most Sunni Muslims, or was so in past centuries, but the reverse is not true). Note that these slaughter rules are skin-in-the-game driven, inherited from the ancient Eastern Mediterranean [discussed in Chapter] Greek and Semitic practice to only worship the gods if one has skin in the game, sacrifice meat to the divinity, and eat what’s left. The Gods do not like cheap signaling.

Now consider this manifestation of the dictatorship of the minority. In the United Kingdom, where the (practicing) Muslim population is only three to four percent, a very high number of the meat we find is halal. Close to seventy percent of lamb imports from New Zealand are halal. Close to ten percent of the chain Subway carry halal-only stores (meaning no pork), in spite of the high costs from the loss of business of nonpork stores. The same holds in South Africa where, with the same proportion of Muslims, a disproportionately higher number of chicken is Halal certified. But in the U.K. and other Christian countries, halal is not neutral enough to reach a high level, as people may use other people’s religious norms. For instance, the 7th Century Christian Arab poet Al-Akhtal made a point to never eat halal meat, in his famous defiant poem boasting his Christianity: “I do not eat sacrificial flesh”

One can expect the same rejection of religious norms to take place in the West as the Muslim populations in Europe grows.

Figure 2 Renormalization group: steps one through three (start from the top): Four boxes containing four boxes, with one of the boxes pink at step one, with successive applications of the minority rule.

So the minority rule may produce a larger share of halal food in the stores than warranted by the proportion of halal eaters in the population, but with a headwind somewhere because some people may have a taboo against Moslem food. But with some non-religious Kashrut rules, so to speak, the share can be expected converge to closer to a hundred percent (or some high number). In the U.S. and Europe, “organic” food companies are selling more and more products precisely because of the minority rule and because ordinary and unlabeled food may be seen by some to contain pesticides, herbicides, and transgenic genetically modified organisms, “GMOs” with, according to them, unknown risks. (What we call GMOs in this context means transgenic food, entailing the transfer of genes from a foreign organism or species). Or it could be for some existential reasons, cautious behavior, or Burkean conservatism –some may not want to venture too far too fast from what their grandparents ate. Labeling something “organic” is a way to say that it contains no transgenic GMOs.

In promoting genetically modified food via all manner of lobbying, purchasing of congressmen, and overt scientific propaganda (with smear campaigns against such persons as yours truly), the big agricultural companies foolishly believed that all they needed was to win the majority. No, you idiots. As I said, your snap “scientific” judgment is too naive in these type of decisions. Consider that transgenic-GMO eaters will eat nonGMOs, but not the reverse. So it may suffice to have a tiny, say no more than five percent of evenly spatially distributed population of non-genetically modified eaters for the entire population to have to eat non-GMO food. How? Say you have a corporate event, a wedding, or a lavish party to celebrate the fall of the Saudi Arabian regime, the bankruptcy of the rent-seeking investment bank Goldman Sachs, or the public reviling of Ray Kotcher, chairman of Ketchum the public relation firm that smears scientists and scientific whistleblowers on behalf of big corporations. Do you need to send a questionnaire asking people if they eat or don’t eat transgenic GMOs and reserve special meals accordingly? No. You just select everything non-GMO, provided the price difference is not consequential. And the price difference appears to be small enough to be negligible as (perishable) food costs in America are largely, about up to eighty or ninety percent, determined by distribution and storage, not the cost at the agricultural level. And as organic food (and designations such as “natural”) is in higher demand, from the minority rule, distribution costs decrease and the minority rule ends up accelerating in its effect.

Big Ag (the large agricultural firms) did not realize that this is the equivalent of entering a game in which one needed to not just win more points than the adversary, but win ninety-seven percent of the total points just to be safe. It is strange, once again, to see Big Ag who spent hundreds of millions of dollars on research cum smear campaigns, with hundreds of these scientists who think of themselves as more intelligent than the rest of the population, miss such an elementary point about asymmetric choices.

Another example: do not think that the spread of automatic shifting cars is necessarily due to the majority of drivers initially preferring automatic; it can just be because those who can drive manual shifts can always drive automatic, but the reciprocal is not true [1].

The method of analysis employed here is called renormalization group, a powerful apparatus in mathematical physics that allows us to see how things scale up (or down). Let us examine it next –without mathematics.

Renormalization Group

Figure 2 shows four boxes exhibiting what is called fractal self-similarity. Each box contains four smaller boxes. Each one of the four boxes will contain four boxes, and so all the way down, and all the way up until we reach a certain level. There are two colors: yellow for the majority choice, and pink for the minority one.

Assume the smaller unit contains four people, a family of four. One of them is in the intransigent minority and eats only nonGMO food (which includes organic). The color of the box is pink and the others yellow . We “renormalize once” as we move up: the stubborn daughter manages to impose her rule on the four and the unit is now all pink, i.e. will opt for nonGMO. Now, step three, you have the family going to a barbecue party attended by three other families. As they are known to only eat nonGMO, the guests will cook only organic. The local grocery store realizing the neighborhood is only nonGMO switches to nonGMO to simplify life, which impacts the local wholesaler, and the stories continues and “renormalizes”.

By some coincidence, the day before the Boston barbecue, I was flaneuring in New York, and I dropped by the office of a friend I wanted to prevent from working, that is, engage in an activity that when abused, causes the loss of mental clarity, in addition to bad posture and loss of definition in the facial features. The French physicist Serge Galam happened to be visiting and chose the friend’s office to kill time. Galam was first to apply these renormalization techniques to social matters and political science; his name was familiar as he is the author of the main book on the subject, which had then been sitting for months in an unopened Amazon box in my basement. He introduced me to his research and showed me a computer model of elections by which it suffices that some minority exceeds a certain level for its choices to prevail.

So the same illusion exists in political discussions, spread by the political “scientists”: you think that because some extreme right or left wing party has, say, the support of ten percent of the population that their candidate would get ten percent of the votes. No: these baseline voters should be classified as “inflexible” and will always vote for their faction. But some of the flexible voters can also vote for that extreme faction, just as nonKosher people can eat Kosher, and these people are the ones to watch out for as they may swell the numbers of votes for the extreme party. Galam’s models produced a bevy of counterintuitive effects in political science –and his predictions turned out to be way closer to real outcomes than the naive consensus.

The Veto

The fact we saw from the renormalization group the “veto” effect as a person in a group can steer choices. Rory Sutherland suggested that this explains why some fast-food chains, such as McDonald thrive, not because they offer a great product, but because they are not vetoed in a certain socio-economic group –and by a small proportions of people in that group at that. To put it in technical terms, it was a best worse-case divergence from expectations: a lower variance and lower mean.

When there are few choices, McDonald’s appears to be a safe bet. It is also a safe bet in shady places with few regulars where the food variance from expectation can be consequential –I am writing these lines in Milan train station and it as offensive as it can be to a visitor from far away, McDonald’s is one of the few restaurants there. Shockingly, one sees Italians there seeking refuge from a risky meal.

Pizza is the same story: it is commonly accepted food and outside a fancy party nobody will be blamed for ordering it.

Rory wrote to me about the asymmetry beer-wine and the choices made for parties: “Once you have ten percent or more women at a party, you cannot serve only beer. But most men will drink wine. So you only need one set of glasses if you serve only wine — the universal donor, to use the language of blood groups.”

Lingua Franca

If a meeting is taking place in Germany in the Teutonic-looking conference room of a corporation that is sufficiently international or European, and one of the persons in the room doesn’t speak German, the entire meeting will be run in… English, the brand of inelegant English used in corporations across the world. That way they can equally offend their Teuronic ancestors and the English language[2]. It all started with the asymmetric rule that those who are nonnative in English know (bad) English, but the reverse (English speakers knowing other languages) is less likely. French was supposed to be the language of diplomacy as civil servants coming from aristocratic background used it –while their more vulgar compatriots involved in commerce relied on English. In the rivalry between the two languages, English won as commerce grew to dominate modern life; the victory it has nothing to do with the prestige of France or the efforts of their civil servants in promoting their more or less beautiful Latinized and logically spelled language over the orthographically confusing one of trans-Channel meat-pie eaters.

We can thus get some intuition on how the emergence of lingua franca languages can come from minority rules–and that is a point that is not visible to linguists. Aramaic is a Semitic language which succeeded Canaanite (that is, Phoenician-Hebrew) in the Levant and resembles Arabic; it was the language Jesus Christ spoke. The reason it came to dominate the Levant and Egypt isn’t because of any particular imperial Semitic power or the fact that they have interesting noses. It was the Persians –who speak an Indo-European language –who spread Aramaic, the language of Assyria, Syria, and Babylon. Persians taught Egyptians a language that was not their own. Simply, when the Persians invaded Babylon they found an administration with scribes who could only use Aramaic and didn’t know Persian, so Aramaic became the state language. If your secretary can only take dictation in Aramaic, Aramaic is what you will use. This led to the oddity of Aramaic being used in Mongolia, as records were maintained in the Syriac alphabet (Syriac is the Eastern dialect of Aramaic). And centuries later, the story would repeat itself in reverse, with the Arabs using Greek in their early administration in the seventh and eighth’s centuries. For during the Hellenistic era, Greek replaced Aramaic as the lingua franca in the Levant, and the scribes of Damascus maintained their records in Greek. But it was not the Greeks who spread Greek around the Mediterranean –Alexander (himself not Greek but Macedonian and spoke Greek as second language, don’t discuss this with a Greek as it infuriates them) did not lead to an immediate deep cultural Hellenization. It was the Romans who accelerated the spreading of Greek, as they used it in their administration across the Eastern empire.

A French Canadian friend from Montreal, Jean-Louis Rheault, commented as follows, bemoaning the loss of language of French Canadians outside narrowly provincial areas. He said: “In Canada, when we say bilingual, it is English speaking and when we say “French speaking” it becomes bilingual.”

The One-Way Street of Religions

In the same manner, the spread of Islam in the Near East where Christianity was heavily entrenched (it was born there) can be attributed to two simple asymmetries. The original Islamic rulers weren’t particularly interested in converting Christians as these provided them with tax revenues –the proselytism of Islam did not address those called “people of the book”, i.e. individuals of Abrahamic faith. In fact, my ancestors who survived thirteen centuries under Muslim rule saw advantages in not being Muslim: mostly in the avoidance of military conscription.

The two asymmetric rules were are as follows. First, if a non Muslim man under the rule of Islam marries a Muslim woman, he needs to convert to Islam –and if either parents of a child happens to be Muslim, the child will be Muslim[3]. Second, becoming Muslim is irreversible, as apostasy is the heaviest crime under the religion, sanctioned by the death penalty. The famous Egyptian actor Omar Sharif, born Mikhael Demetri Shalhoub, was of Lebanese Christian origins. He converted to Islam to marry a famous Egyptian actress and had to change his name to an Arabic one. He later divorced, but did not revert to the faith of his ancestors.

Under these two asymmetric rules, one can do simple simulations and see how a small Islamic group occupying Christian (Coptic) Egypt can lead, over the centuries, to the Copts becoming a tiny minority. All one needs is a small rate of interfaith marriages. Likewise, one can see how Judaism doesn’t spread and tends to stay in the minority, as the religion has opposite rules: the mother is required to be Jewish, causing interfaith marriages to leave the community. An even stronger asymmetry than that of Judaism explains the depletion in the Near East of three Gnostic faiths: the Druze, the Ezidi, and the Mandeans (Gnostic religions are those with mysteries and knowledge that is typically accessible to only a minority of elders, with the rest of the members in the dark about the details of the faith). Unlike Islam that requires either parents to be Muslim, and Judaism that asks for at least the mother to have the faith, these three religions require both parents to be of the faith, otherwise the person says toodaloo to the community.

Egypt has a flat terrain. The distribution of the population presents homogeneous mixtures there, which permits renormalization (i.e. allows the asymmetric rule to prevail) –we saw earlier in the chapter that for Kosher rules to work, one needed Jews to be somewhat spread out across the country. But in places such as Lebanon, Galilee, and Northern Syria, with mountainous terrain, Christians and other Non Sunni Muslims remained concentrated. Christians not being exposed to Muslims, experienced no intermarriage.

Egypt’s Copts suffered from another problem: the irreversibility of Islamic conversions. Many Copts during Islamic rule converted to Islam when it was merely an administrative procedure, something that helps one land a job or handle a problem that requires Islamic jurisprudence. One do not have to really believe in it since Islam doesn’t conflict markedly with Orthodox Christianity. Little by little a Christian or Jewish family bearing the marrano-style conversion becomes truly converted, as, a couple of generations later, the descendants forget the arrangement of their ancestors.

So all Islam did was out-stubborn Christianity, which itself won thanks to its own stubbornness. For, before Islam, the original spread of Christianity in the Roman empire can be largely seen due to… the blinding intolerance of Christians, their unconditional, aggressive and proselyting recalcitrance. Roman pagans were initially tolerant of Christians, as the tradition was to share gods with other members of the empire. But they wondered why these Nazarenes didn’t want to give and take gods and offer that Jesus fellow to the Roman pantheon in exchange for some other gods. What, our gods aren’t good enough for them? But Christians were intolerant of Roman paganism. The “persecutions” of the Christians had vastly more to do with the intolerance of the Christians for the pantheon and local gods, than the reverse. What we read is history written by the Christian side, not the Greco-Roman one. [4]

We know too little about the Roman side during the rise of Christianity, as hagiographies have dominated the discourse: we have for instance the narrative of the martyr Saint Catherine, who kept converting her jailors until she was beheaded, except that… she may have never existed. There are endless histories of Christian martyrs and saints –but very little about the other side, Pagan heroes. All we have is the bit we know about the reversion to Christianity during the emperor Julian’s apostasy and the writings of his entourage of Syrian-Greek pagans such as Libanius Antiochus. Julian had tried to go back to Ancient Paganism in vain: it was like trying to keep a balloon under water. And it was not because the majority was pagan as historians mistakenly think: it was because the Christian side was too unyielding. Christianity had great minds such as Gregorius of Nazianzen and Basil of Caesaria, but nothing to match the great orator Libanius, not even close. (My heuristic is that the more pagan, the more brilliant one’s mind, and the higher one’s ability to handle nuances and ambiguity. Purely monotheistic religious such as Protestant Christianity, Salafi Islam, or fundamentalist atheism accommodate literalist and mediocre minds that cannot handle ambiguity.)

In fact we can observe in the history of Mediterranean “religions” or, rather, rituals and systems of behavior and belief, a drift dictated by the intolerant, actually bringing the system closer to what we can call a religion. Judaism might have almost lost because of the mother-rule and the confinement to a tribal base, but Christianity ruled, and for the very same reasons, Islam did. Islam? there have been many Islams, the final accretion quite different from the earlier ones. For Islam itself is ending up being taken over (in the Sunni branch) by the purists simply because these were more intolerant than the rest: the Wahhabis, founders of Saudi Arabia, were the ones who destroyed the shrines, and to impose the maximally intolerant rule, in a manner that was later imitated by “ISIS” (the Islamic State of Iraq and Syria/the Levant). Every single accretion of Sunni Islam seems to be there to accommodate the most intolerant of its branches.

Imposing Virtue on Others

This idea of one-sidedness can help us debunk a few more misconceptions. How do books get banned? Certainly not because they offend the average person –most persons are passive and don’t really care, or don’t care enough to request the banning. It looks like, from past episodes, that all it takes is a few (motivated) activists for the banning of some books, or the black-listing of some people. The great philosopher and logician Bertrand Russell lost his job at the City University of New York owing to a letter by an angry –and stubborn –mother who did not wish to have her daughter in the same room as the fellow with dissolute lifestyle and unruly ideas. [5]

The same seems to apply to prohibitions –at least the prohibition of alcohol in the United States which led to interesting Mafia stories.

Let us conjecture that the formation of moral values in society doesn’t come from the evolution of the consensus. No, it is the most intolerant person who imposes virtue on others precisely because of that intolerance. The same can apply to civil rights.

An insight as to how the mechanisms of religion and transmission of morals obey the same renormalization dynamics as dietary laws –and how we can show that morality is more likely to be something enforced by a minority. We saw earlier in the chapter the asymmetry between obeying and breaking rules: a law-abiding (or rule abiding) fellow always follows the rules, but a felon or someone with looser sets of principles will not always break the rules. Likewise we discussed the strong asymmetric effects of the halal dietary laws. Let us merge the two. It turns out that, in classical Arabic, the term halal has one opposite: haram. Violating legal and moral rules –any rule — is called haram. It is the exact same interdict that governs food intake and all other human behaviors, like sleeping with the wife of the neighbor, lending with interest (without partaking of downside of the borrower) or killing one’s landlord for pleasure. Haram is haram and is asymmetric.

From that we can see that once a moral rule is established, it would suffice to have a small intransigent minority of geographically distributed followers to dictate the norm in society. The sad news, as we will see in the next chapter, is that one person looking at mankind as an aggregate may mistakenly believe that humans are spontaneously becoming more moral, better, more gentle, have better breath, when it applies to only a small proportion of mankind.

Popper’s Paradox

As I am writing these lines, people are disputing whether the freedom of the enlightened West can be undermined by the intrusive policies that would be needed to fight Salafi fundamentalists.

Clearly can democracy –by definition the majority — tolerate enemies? The question is as follows: “ Would you agree to deny the freedom of speech to every political party that has in its charter the banning the freedom of speech?” Let’s go one step further, “Should a society that has elected to be tolerant be intolerant about intolerance?”

This is in fact the incoherence that Kurt Gödel (the grandmaster of logical rigor) detected in the constitution while taking the naturalization exam. Legend has it that Gödel started arguing with the judge and Einstein, who was his witness during the process, saved him.

I wrote about people with logical flaws asking me if one should be “skeptical about skepticism”; I used a similar answer as Popper when was asked if “ one could falsify falsification”.

We can answer these points using the minority rule. Yes, an intolerant minority can control and destroy democracy. Actually, as we saw, it will eventually destroy our world.

So, we need to be more than intolerant with some intolerant minorities. It is not permissible to use “American values” or “Western principles” in treating intolerant Salafism (which denies other peoples’ right to have their own religion). The West is currently in the process of committing suicide.

The Irreverence of Markets and Science

Now consider markets. We can say that markets aren’t the sum of market participants, but price changes reflect the activities of the most motivated buyer and seller. Yes, the most motivated rules. Indeed this is something that only traders seem to understand: why a price can drop by ten percent because of a single seller. All you need is a stubborn seller. Markets react in a way that is disproportional to the impetus. The overall stock markets represent currently more than thirty trillions dollars but a single order in 2008, only fifty billion, that is less than two tenth of a percent of the total, caused them to drop by close to ten percent, causing losses of around three trillion. It was an order activated by the Parisian Bank Société Générale who discovered a hidden acquisition by a rogue trader and wanted to reverse the purchase. Why did the market react so disproportionately? Because the order was one-way –stubborn — there was desire to sell but no way to change one’s mind. My personal adage is:

The market is like a large movie theatre with a small door.

And the best way to detect a sucker (say the usual finance journalist) is to see if his focus is on the size of the door or on that of the theater. Stampedes happen in cinemas, say when someone shouts “fire”, because those who want to be out do not want to stay in, exactly the same unconditionality we saw with Kosher observance.

Science acts similarly. We will return later with a discussion of how the minority rule is behind Karl Popper’s approach to science. But let us for now discuss the more entertaining Feynman. What do You Care What Other People Think? is the title of a book of anecdotes by the great Richard Feynman, the most irreverent and playful scientist of his day. As reflected in the title of the book, Feynman conveys in it the idea of the fundamental irreverence of science, acting through a similar mechanism as the Kosher asymmetry. How? Science isn’t the sum of what scientists think, but exactly as with markets, a procedure that is highly skewed. Once you debunk something, it is now wrong (that is how science operates but let’s ignore disciplines such as economics and political science that are more like pompous entertainment). Had science operated by majority consensus we would be still stuck in the Middle Ages and Einstein would have ended as he started, a patent clerk with fruitless side hobbies.

***

Alexander said that it was preferable to have an army of sheep led by a lion to an army of lions led by a sheep. Alexander (or no doubt he who produced this probably apocryphal saying) understood the value of the active, intolerant, and courageous minority. Hannibal terrorized Rome for a decade and a half with a tiny army of mercenaries, winning twenty-two battles against the Romans, battles in which he was outnumbered each time. He was inspired by a version of this maxim. At the battle of Cannae, he remarked to Gisco who complained that the Carthaginians were outnumbered by the Romans: “There is one thing that’s more wonderful than their numbers … in all that vast number there is not one man called Gisgo.[6][i]

Unus sed leo: only one but a lion.

This large payoff from stubborn courage is not just in the military. The entire growth of society, whether economic or moral, comes from a small number of people. So we close this chapter with a remark about the role of skin in the game in the condition of society. Society doesn’t evolve by consensus, voting, majority, committees, verbose meeting, academic conferences, and polling; only a few people suffice to disproportionately move the needle. All one needs is an asymmetric rule somewhere. And asymmetry is present in about everything.

Notes

[1] Thank Amir-Reza Amini.

[2] Thank Arnie Schwarzvogel.

[3] Note some minor variations across regions and Islamic sects. The original rule is that if a Muslim woman marries a Non Muslim man, he needs to convert. In practice, in many countries, both need to do so.

[4] The various modes of worship, which prevailed in the Roman world, were all considered by the people, as equally true; by the philosopher, as equally false; and by the magistrate, as equally useful. And thus toleration produced not only mutual indulgence, but even religious concord. Gibbon

[5] “Never doubt that a small group of thoughtful citizens can change the world. Indeed, it is the only thing that ever has.” — Margaret Mead

[6] The Carthaginians seem to be short in name variety: there are plenty of Hamilcars and Hadsrupals confusing historians. Likewise there appear to be many Giscos, including the character in Flaubert’s Salambo.

[i] http://ift.tt/2aRL4O9



from Hacker News http://ift.tt/YV9WJO
via IFTTT

Am I Introverted, or Just Rude?

http://ift.tt/2dsE5ko


If they could do it, why not me?

Around the same time as the publication of “Quiet,” in 2013, I turned 40, and achieved a certain level of professional success. It seemed like permission not to try quite so hard. At first, saying “no” to fund-raisers and coffees brought with it a keen, almost illicit pleasure. What freedom! I started slipping out of meetings and school assemblies at the first possible moment instead of staying to chat. On one delicious occasion, I sat in my car and read a book while my children attended a family-oriented athletic function.

It was all so easy to excuse. I wasn’t neglecting my friends, avoiding my fellow parents or letting my community engagements suffer. I was preserving my energy, engaging in self-care, allowing my “tortoise shell” to protect my vulnerable, precious self. I’d spent so long accommodating the world’s demand that I get out there and participate. Finally, the world seemed willing to accommodate me.

There is no research correlating the number of books on introversion with the number of cocktails not consumed by people not going out for drinks after work. But a spate of articles and social media posts on the glories of staying home in one’s pj’s suggests that I am not the only one who went overboard once the “introvert” label came to imply a deep thinker with a rich inner life rather than a lone gunman.

Society has a rich history of people seizing on social evolution as an excuse for bad manners. From the Romantic poets to the transcendentalists to the Summer of Love hippies, many have rejected a supposed facade of good behavior in favor of being true to their inner nature. Good manners are mere mannerisms, the argument goes, which serve only to put barriers in the way of deeper connections.

There’s another argument to be made, though, that those deeper connections are the easy ones. It’s the looser ties, the ones that have to be created or re-created at each meeting, that are tough. Life is largely lived among acquaintances and strangers. So many fall into problematic categories: some appear different or unapproachable, some we actively dislike, some we’ve failed to connect with in the past. What do we have to gain from even trying?

A lot, as it turns out. When I skip big gatherings of strangers, I’m not just being a little rude to the individual people around me, I’m being uncivil in a larger sense. The more we isolate ourselves from new people, the more isolated and segregated our society is likely to become. Those casual interactions in dog runs and at kids’ hockey games are the ones that are most likely to cross social and economic barriers. They expand my little world as well as the overlapping bubbles that create a society.

We can respect our own introversion, and embrace the “quiet” people among us, without abandoning every challenging interaction. When I asked Ms. Cain (while interviewing her about introversion in teenagers) if self-indulgent introverts risked crossing the line into antisocial behavior — if we might, in fact, just be being rude — she laughed, and agreed. Sometimes, she said, “you have to consider the other person’s point of view instead of getting wrapped up in your own discomfort.”

“You don’t have to feel like you have to do what the group is doing,” she said, but “the knowledge that you might inadvertently be hurting someone’s feelings by not showing up or by behaving in a way that’s perceived as aloof can make it easier to extend yourself.”

Extending ourselves can actually be good for us. We forget that we don’t always know what makes us happy. We predict that we prefer solitude on our commute, for example, but consistently report a more positive experience when we connect with a stranger. That doesn’t have to mean we abandon our book to an hourlong discussion of the merits of our seatmate’s grandchildren. We can embrace both the graceful brief conversation and the retreat into headphones.

In his book, “If You’re So Smart, Why Aren’t You Happy,” the behaviorist Raj Raghunathan describes studies suggesting that prosocial behavior makes us happier, even when that behavior comes at a material cost to ourselves: Toddlers are happiest when they give monkey puppets treats from their own stash, adults in rich and poor countries alike reported feeling happier when they spent a small sum of their own money on others rather than on themselves.

Years ago, I was habitually late. “I can’t help it!” I declared to an expert in time management (I’d turned my effort to reform into a magazine article, as writers do, which gave me the excuse to seek professional help).

“Have you ever missed a plane?” she asked. I had not. “Then you can help it. You just care more about yourself than about the needs of others.”

I may be naturally reserved, and more comfortable alone than I will ever be in a crowd, but I am not at the mercy of my nature. There are many excuses for failing to conduct ourselves with courtesy, for avoiding gatherings and conversations we don’t think we will enjoy, or for just putting on our pajamas and staying home. Too many of them boil down to just that one thing: We care more about ourselves than about the needs of others.

That’s not about introversion. It’s just an ordinary version of selfishness.

Continue reading the main story


from Hacker News http://ift.tt/YV9WJO
via IFTTT

How to listen when you disagree

http://ift.tt/2axbQ1Q


So, I asked:

“Thank you for sharing that. Tell me your story? I’d love to know how you came to this point of view.”

She seemed surprised by my interest.

“Why? It doesn’t matter. Your sign said Free Listening, so I gave you something to listen to.”

“Give me more to listen to.”

“They should be locked up! It’s wrong. It’s not right to go out and sleep with whoever, then just vacuum away the result like it never happened.”

She paused…then inhaled the entire world.

“And it’s not fair. All I’ve ever wanted to be is a mom. My whole life, I knew I was meant to have children. Then, when I was 18—18!—the doctor told me I’d never have children. My ovaries were damaged, or missing...it doesn’t matter which. I kept it a secret, and when my husband found out, he left me. I’m alone, my body doesn’t work, I’m old…who will ever love me…”

I wondered if she could hear my heart breaking.

“…so, I guess I get upset when I see people who can get pregnant, who can have kids, who’s bodies work…who can be moms…and they just choose not to…”

Sometimes, there’s nothing to “disagree” with.

I didn’t need to be right.  

I just needed to be there.

She wiped away a few tears, gave me a hug, and thanked me for listening.

She exhaled, and walked back into the RNC circus.

Maybe one day, she’ll hear my story.  But today, it was my turn to hear hers.

I hope she felt loved.



from Hacker News http://ift.tt/YV9WJO
via IFTTT

First Ever Quadriplegic Treated with Stem Cells Regains Upper Body Motor Control

http://ift.tt/2d418xn

First Ever Quadriplegic Treated With Stem Cells Regains Motor Control in His Upper Body

kris-boesen-keck-medicine-of-usc

For the first time ever, neuroscientists have treated a total quadriplegic with stem cells, and he has substantially recovered the functions of his upper body only two months into the process.

The Keck Medical Center of USC announced that a team of doctors became the first in California to inject an experimental treatment made from stem cells, AST-OPC1, into the damaged cervical spine of a recently paralyzed 21-year-old man as part of a multi-center clinical trial.

On March 6, just shy of his 21st birthday, Kristopher (Kris) Boesen of Bakersfield suffered a traumatic injury to his cervical spine when his car fishtailed on a wet road, hit a tree, and slammed into a telephone pole.

MOREThese New Alternatives For the EpiPen Will Cost Less Than $100

Parents Rodney and Annette Boesen were warned there was a good chance their son would be permanently paralyzed from the neck down. However, they also learned that Kris could possibly qualify for a clinical study that might help.

Leading the surgical team and working in collaboration with Rancho Los Amigos National Rehabilitation Center and Keck Medicine of USC, Charles Liu, MD, PhD, director of the USC Neurorestoration Center, injected an experimental dose of 10 million AST-OPC1 cells directly into Kris’ cervical spinal cord in early April.

“Typically, spinal cord injury patients undergo surgery that stabilizes the spine but generally does very little to restore motor or sensory function,” explains Liu. “With this study, we are testing a procedure that may improve neurological function, which could mean the difference between being permanently paralyzed and being able to use one’s arms and hands. Restoring that level of function could significantly improve the daily lives of patients with severe spinal injuries.”

CHECK OUT: Simple Blood Test Could Detect Cancer Ten Years Before Symptoms Show

Two weeks after surgery, Kris began to show signs of improvement. Three months later, he’s able to feed himself, use his cell phone, write his name, operate a motorized wheelchair and hug his friends and family. Improved sensation and movement in both arms and hands also makes it easier for Kris to care for himself, and to envision a life lived more independently.

“As of 90 days post-treatment, Kris has gained significant improvement in his motor function, up to two spinal cord levels,” said Dr. Liu. “In Kris’ case, two spinal cord levels means the difference between using your hands to brush your teeth, operate a computer or do other things you wouldn’t otherwise be able to do, so having this level of functional independence cannot be overstated.”

Doctors are careful not to predict Kris’ future progress.

RELATEDFDA Finally Bans Antibacterial Soaps Containing Triclosan and 18 Other Chemicals

“All I’ve wanted from the beginning was a fighting chance,” said Kris, who has a passion for fixing up and driving sports cars and was studying to become a life insurance broker at the time of the accident. “But if there’s a chance for me to walk again, then heck yeah! I want to do anything possible to do that.”

Because the window for performing the surgery was tight, everything needed to go according to schedule in order for Kris to qualify.

Once Kris made the decision to pursue enrollment in the study, dozens of doctors, nurses, rehabilitation specialists and others sprang into action. Because he would need to provide voice confirmation of his desire to participate in the study, Kris had to be able to breathe without a ventilator. Weaning a patient from assisted breathing generally is a three-week process. He did it in five days with the help of a respiratory care team. He signed the paperwork and began a week of assessments, scans and other pre-surgery tests.

MOREAfter Marrying On Her ‘Deathbed,’ This Bride Made a Miraculous Recovery After Quitting 1 Food

In early April, a surgical team from Keck Hospital of USC carefully injected 10 million AST-OPC1 cells directly into Kris’ cervical spine. Nearly six weeks later, Kris was discharged and returned to Bakersfield to continue his rehabilitation. Doctors reviewed his progress at seven days, 30 days, 60 days and 90 days post-injection, and Kris can look forward to detailed assessments after 180 days, 270 days and one year.

Rodney and Annette Boesen say they are amazed at the level of collaboration and cooperation that enabled their son to participate in the study. “So many things had to happen, and there were so many things that could have put up a roadblock,” marvels Rodney. “The people at Keck Medical Center of USC and elsewhere moved heaven and earth to get things done. There was never a moment through all of this when we didn’t think our son was getting world class care.”

CHECK OUTGrandfather Donates Kidney, Sparks Idea for Voucher Program That is Spreading Life

The pioneering surgery is the latest example of how the emerging fields of neurorestoration and regenerative medicine may have the potential to improve the lives of thousands of patients who have suffered a severe spinal cord injury.

The stem cell procedure Kris received is part of a Phase 1/2a clinical trial that is evaluating the safety and efficacy of escalating doses of AST-OPC1 cells developed by Fremont, California-based Asterias Biotherapeutics. AST-OPC1 cells are made from embryonic stem cells by carefully converting them into oligodendrocyte progenitor cells (OPCs), which are cells found in the brain and spinal cord that support the healthy functioning of nerve cells. In previous laboratory studies, AST-OPC1 was shown to produce neurotrophic factors, stimulate vascularization and induce remyelination of denuded axons. All are critical factors in the survival, regrowth and conduction of nerve impulses through axons at the injury site, according to Edward D. Wirth III, MD, PhD, chief medical director of Asterias and lead investigator of the study, dubbed “SCiStar.”

RELATEDDental Fillings Heal Teeth With Stem Cells

“At the 10 million cell level, we’re now in a dose range that is the human equivalent of where we were when we saw efficacy in pre-clinical studies,” says Wirth. “While we continue to evaluate safety first and foremost, we are also now looking at how well treatment might help restore movement in these patients.”

To qualify for the clinical trial, enrollees must be between the age of 18 and 69, and their condition must be stable enough to receive an injection of AST-OPC1 between the fourteenth and thirtieth days following injury.

Keck is one of six sites in the U.S. authorized to enroll subjects and administer the clinical trial dosage.

Treat Your Friends To Some Positivity: Click To SharePhoto by Keck Medicine of USC



from Hacker News http://ift.tt/YV9WJO
via IFTTT